Misplaced Pages

Semi-proportional representation: Difference between revisions

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
Browse history interactively← Previous editContent deleted Content addedVisualWikitext
Revision as of 15:23, 24 October 2017 editRhys Goldstein (talk | contribs)217 edits Restoring 29 Feb 2016 edit by BarrelProof.← Previous edit Latest revision as of 18:39, 11 September 2024 edit undoOrbitalbuzzsaw (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users3,814 edits Single-vote systemsTag: Visual edit 
(70 intermediate revisions by 22 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Short description|Family of electoral systems}}{{Split|date=August 2024|Winner-take-most representation|discuss=Talk:Semi-proportional representation#Split distinct meanings}}{{Electoral systems}}
{{Electoral systems}}
A '''Semi-proportional''' voting system is a multi-winner voting system which allows representation of minorities, but does not reflect the strength of the competing political forces proportionally, mixing the principles of ] and ].<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.mtholyoke.edu/acad/polit/damy/BeginnningReading/semiproportional.htm|title=Semiproportional voting systems|accessdate=19 June 2011|author=Douglas J. Amy}}</ref><ref>], ''Parties and Party Systems. A framework for analysis.'' ], Cambridge University Press.</ref> '''Semi-proportional representation''' characterizes multi-winner ]s which allow representation of minorities, but are not intended to reflect the strength of the competing political forces in close proportion to the votes they receive.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.mtholyoke.edu/acad/polit/damy/BeginnningReading/semiproportional.htm|title=Semiproportional voting systems|accessdate=19 June 2011|author=Douglas J. Amy}}</ref> Semi-proportional voting systems are generally used as a compromise between complex and expensive but more-] systems (like the ]) and simple ] systems.<ref>{{Cite book|author=Giovanni Sartori|author-link=Giovanni Sartori|title=Parties and Party Systems. A framework for analysis|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=ywr0CcGDNHwC|publisher=]|date=2005|isbn=9780954796617}}</ref><ref>{{Cite book|author=Douglas J. Amy|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=-G46rVRXkY0C|title=Behind the Ballot Box: A Citizen's Guide to Voting Systems|publisher=]|date=2000|isbn=9780275965860}}</ref> Examples of semi-proportional systems include the ], ], and ].


==Semi-proportional systems== ==Semi-proportional systems==
While most proportional representation systems are to some extent semi proportional due to thresholds, or split electoral regions, this article deals more with mixed systems, that are to an extent proportional but not designed to be as proportional as possible across an entire country. Most proportional representation systems will not yield precisely proportional outcomes due to the use of ]s, small electoral regions, or other implementation details that vary from one elected body to another. However, systems that yield results close to the ideal are generally considered fully-proportional.


The choice to use a semi-proportional voting system may be a deliberate attempt to find a balance between majority rule and proportional representation: semi-proportional systems can allow for fairer representation of those parties that have difficulty gaining individual seats while still keeping the possibility of one party gaining a majority when there is a ]. The choice to use a semi-proportional electoral system may be a deliberate attempt to find a balance between single-party rule and proportional representation. Semi-proportional systems can allow for fairer representation of those parties that have difficulty gaining even a single seat while retaining the possibility of one party gaining an overall majority of seats even if it receives less than a majority of the votes; they can ensure that the two or three largest parties all have their due share of seats or more while not producing representation for the smallest parties.


Because there are many measures of proportionality,<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.votingmatters.org.uk/ISSUE20/I20P4.PDF|title=Apportionment and Proportionality: A Measured View|author=P. Kestelman|accessdate=19 June 2011|date=June 2005}}</ref><ref name="WeingastWittman2006">{{cite book|author1=Barry R. Weingast|author2=Donald A. Wittman|title=The Oxford handbook of political economy|url=http://books.google.com/books?id=TTw9Ar4a2uEC&pg=PA105|accessdate=19 June 2011|date=19 October 2006|publisher=Oxford University Press|isbn=978-0-19-927222-8|pages=105–}}</ref> and because there is no objective threshold, opinions on what constitutes a semi-proportional method rather than a majoritarian or a fully proportional one, may differ. Because there are many measures of proportionality,<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.votingmatters.org.uk/ISSUE20/I20P4.PDF|title=Apportionment and Proportionality: A Measured View|author=P. Kestelman|accessdate=19 June 2011|date=June 2005}}</ref><ref name="WeingastWittman2006">{{cite book|author1=Barry R. Weingast|author2=Donald A. Wittman|title=The Oxford handbook of political economy|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=TTw9Ar4a2uEC&pg=PA105|accessdate=19 June 2011|date=19 October 2006|publisher=Oxford University Press|isbn=978-0-19-927222-8|pages=105–}}</ref> and because there is no objective threshold, opinions may differ on what constitutes a semi-proportional system as opposed to a non-proportional one or a fully proportional system.


===Non-partisan systems=== ==Single-vote systems==
Methods where parties can only achieve proportionality by coordinating their voters are usually considered to be semi-proportional.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://prfound.org/basics/related/semi-proportional/|title=Semi-Proportional Electoral Methods|accessdate=19 June 2011}}</ref> They are not majoritarian, since in the perfect case, the outcome will be proportional, but they are not proportional either, since such a perfect case requires a very high degree of coordination. Such methods include the ] and ], the latter of which becomes less proportional the more votes each voter has. The ] also allows minority representation, concentrating votes over the number of candidates that every minor party thinks it can support. Election systems in which a party can achieve its due share of seats (proportionality) only by coordinating its voters are usually considered to be semi-proportional.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://prfound.org/basics/related/semi-proportional/|title=Semi-Proportional Electoral Methods|accessdate=19 June 2011}}</ref> They are not non-proportional or majoritarian, since in the perfect case the outcome will be proportional, but they are not proportional either, since the perfect case is not guaranteed without coordination. Such systems include the ] and ], both of which are commonly used to achieve approximately-proportional outcomes while maintaining simplicity and reducing the cost of ]. Under these systems, parties often coordinate voters by limiting the size of the party slate, or by using complex ] schemes where voters are asked to randomize which candidate(s) they support.


This group of system are, at least ''technically'', non-partisan. Surely, group of candidates can coordinate their campaigns, and ''politically'' present themselves as party members, but there is no obligation for electors to respect these party links, and forms of ] are usually possible. These systems are notable for the absence of an ordered ]. Candidates may coordinate their campaigns, and present or be presented as agents of a party, but voters may choose to support one candidate among the said group but not the others (that is, ] is permitted).


===Single Transferable Vote=== ===Single transferable vote===
Some consider STV to be a semi proportional system. The degree of proportionality across the a country depends on the average size of constituency used, in the 2011 Irish general election Fine Gael came just 9 (4.8%) seats short of an overall majority with just 36.1% of the vote, however the result of the election was exceptional and Fine Gael benefited from a high level of transfers from those who did not rank them first. It is possible under STV to win an overall majority with significantly fewer than 50% of the votes, but this is only if the party also gains a high level of transfers from those who do not rank them first. As it lacks any arbitrary nationwide ] even with the Irish 3-5 seat system the level of proportionality does not veer too far from countries with such thresholds.


Many writers consider the ] to be a semi-proportional system because of its substantial favoritism towards major parties, generally caused by a combination of the ] in small districts, as well as the substantial degree of ] involved when there are ]s.<ref name=NorrisChoosingElecSys>{{cite web|last=Norris|first=Pippa|title=Choosing Electoral Systems: Proportional, Majoritarian and Mixed Systems|url=http://www.hks.harvard.edu/fs/pnorris/Acrobat/Choosing%20Electoral%20Systems.pdf|publisher=]|year=1997}}</ref> On the other hand, some authors describe it as a proportional system, on the grounds that it is theoretically ] in the limit of infinitely-large constituencies.<ref>David M. Farrell Electoral Systems (2011)</ref> However, it is worth noting that STV is only proportional for ], i.e. if voters rank candidates first by party and only then by candidate. As such, the proportionality of STV breaks down if voters are ]s or choose to support candidates of different parties.
===Partisan systems===
Other forms of semi-proportional representation are based, or at least use, ]s to work. Looking to the electoral systems effectively in use around the world, there are three general methods to reinforce the ] starting from basic PR mechanisms: ], ]es, and extremely reduced ] magnitude. An ] may reinforce majorities if the proportion of compensatory seats is too low.


A major complication with proportionality under STV is the need for ]; small constituencies are strongly disproportional, but large constituencies make it difficult or impossible for voters to rank large numbers of candidates, turning the election into a ''de facto'' ] ] system, particularly where voters lack any meaningful information about the candidates on their ballot.
A ] introduce a FPTP-like idea in multi-member constituencies. The bonus gives additional seats to the first party or alliance, to create a ] as it happens in countries using the ] even if single-member constituencies are not in use. The ] system was firstly introduced by ] to win the ], but it was later used in ] again, with additional democratic limits, and then expanded in some neighbor countries like ], ] and ].


The degree of proportionality of the results in a district (and when combined with other district results, the proportionality of results across a country) depends on the number of seats elected in the district. In the ], Fine Gael received 45.2% of the seats with just 36.1% of the first preference votes. In the ], the ] received 50% more votes than the ], but both parties won the same number of seats. ] uses districts of 3-7 members.
The most simple mechanism to reinforce major parties in PR system is a severely reduced constituency magnitude, so to reduce the possibility for minor national parties to gain seats. If the ] ] is still considered a form of ], the ] used in ] effectively establish by law a two-party rule over the country.


Similarly, the ] resulted in the ]s winning more seats than the ] with a smaller share of the vote.
The last main group usually considered semi-proportional consists of ] models. The system used for the ] since 1996 is considered a parallel voting system, modified by a list-seat ceiling (8%) for over-representation of parties. The "]" system used for the ] from 1993 to 2005 and the electoral system for the ] since 1990 are also special cases.


The proportionality of STV can be controversial, especially in close elections like the 1981 election in Malta. In this election, the ] won a majority of seats despite the Nationalist Party winning a majority of ''first preference'' votes. This caused a constitutional crisis, leading to a provision to provide bonus seats in case of disproportional results. These bonus seats were needed in 1987, 1996, and 2008 to prevent further ].
As well, the ]s where the additional members are not sufficient to balance the disproportionality of the original system can produce less than proportional results, especially in the ] where only 33.3% of members are compensatory. The electoral system commonly referred to in Britain as the "additional member system" is also used for the ], and the ], with generally proportional results.

The degree of proportionality nationwide is strongly related to the number of seats to be filled in each constituency. In a three-seat constituency using the ], a full quarter of the vote is ]. In a nine-seat constituency, only a tenth of the vote is ], and a party needs only 10% of the vote to win a seat. Consequently, the best proportionality is achieved when there are a large number of representatives per constituency. The ] is theoretically ], allowing some of the errors in apportionment to cancel out if voters across the whole country. However, it also increases the vulnerability of STV to ] by large parties, allowing them to win the same number of seats they would have won under Droop.

== Partisan systems ==
Other forms of semi-proportional representation are based on, or at least use, ]s to work. Looking to the electoral systems effectively in use around the world, there are three general methods to reinforce the ] principle of representation (but not necessarily ] or ], see ] and ]) starting from basic PR mechanisms: ], the majority bonus system (MBS), and extremely reduced ] magnitude.

In ]s (AMS), the number of additional members may not be sufficient to balance the disproportionality of the original system, thereby producing less than proportional results. When this imbalance is created intentionally, the result could be described as a semi-proportional system — for example, in the ], where only 33.3% of members are compensatory. The electoral system commonly referred to in Britain as the "additional member system" is also used for the ] and the ], with generally proportional results. Similarly, in vote transfer based ] systems, the number of compensatory seats may be too low (or too high) to achieve proportionality.<ref name=":0">{{Cite journal|last=Golosov|first=G. V.|date=2013|title=The Case for Mixed Single Vote Electoral Systems|journal=The Journal of Social, Political, and Economic Studies}}</ref> Such a system is used in Hungary in local elections.<ref>{{Cite web|title=2010. évi L. törvény a helyi önkormányzati képviselők és polgármesterek választásáról|trans-title=Act L. of 2010. on the election of local government representatives and mayors|url=https://net.jogtar.hu/jogszabaly?docid=A1000050.TV|language=hu}}</ref> The "]" system used for the ] from 1993 to 2005 and the electoral system for the ] since 1990 are also special cases, based on parallel voting, but also including compensatory mechanisms – which however are insufficient for providing proportional results.

A ] takes an otherwise proportional system based on multi-member constituencies, and introduces disproportionality by granting additional seats to the first party or alliance. Majority bonuses help produce ] similar to those which occur in elections under ]. The ] system was first introduced by ] to win the ]. It has remained in use in ], as well as seeing some use in ], ], and ].{{Cn|date=June 2024}}

The simplest mechanism to reinforce major parties in PR system is to severely restrict the number of seats per ], which increases the ] (the number of votes needed to be guaranteed a seat).

The last main group usually considered semi-proportional consists of ] models. The system used for the ] since 1996 is considered a parallel voting system, modified by a list-seat ceiling (8%) for over-representation of parties.

== Usage ==
{{Incomplete table|date=June 2024}}{{Unsourced|section|date=June 2024}}
{| class="wikitable sortable"
!Country
!Legislative body
!Latest election (year)
!Type of majoritarian system
!(Seats per
constituency)
!Electoral system
!Total seats
!Governmental system
!Notes
|-
|]
|]
|]
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|2 (local districts) / 14 (nationwide constituency)
|Parallel voting / ''superposition'' (MMM):
] (PBV) locally + ] nationwide
|28
|]
|
|-
|]
|]
|]
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|1–17
|'']'' mixed majoritarian (MMM):
] (FPTP/SMP) in single-member districts and ] in multi-member districts (])
|500
|
|
|-
|]
|]
|]
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|3–28
|''Fusion'' / majority jackpot (MBS):
80% of seats (rounded to the nearest integer) in each constituency are awarded to the party receiving the most votes (]), remaining seats are allocated proportionally to other parties receiving over 10% (], ])
|65
|]
|
|-
|]
|] ]
|]
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|4–17
|Two-round ] (MBS) in multi-member constituencies
|57
|
|
|-
|]
|]
|]
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|1 (local districts),
120 (national constituency)
|Parallel voting / ''superposition'' (MMM):
] (closed list) + ] (FPTP/SMP)
|150
|]
|
|-
|]
|
|
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|
|Majority bonus system (MBS)
|
|
|
|-
|]
|]
|]
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|1 (local districts),
76 (national constituency)
|Parallel voting / ''superposition'' (MMM):
] (]) + ] (FPTP/SMP)
|114
|
|
|-
|]
|] (Országgyűlés)
|]
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|1 (local districts), 93 (national constituency)
|''Supermixed'' / Mixed-member majoritarian (MMM):
] (FPTP/SMP) + national list-PR for 93 seats (combination of ] and ])
|199
|]
|Before the 2014, a different mixed system was used with a two-round system in single-member districts
|-
|]
|
|
|
|
|] (SNTV)
|
|
|
|-
| rowspan="2" |]
|]
|]
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|1 (local districts), 12 (Italians abroad constituency), ?-? (multi-member districts){{Citation needed|date=January 2022}}
|''Superposition'' / Mixed-member majoritarian (MMM) using a single vote
] + ] (FPTP/SMP)
|630
|]
|
|-
|]
|]
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|1 (local districts), 6 (Italians abroad constituency), ?-? (multi-member districts){{Citation needed|date=January 2022}}
|''Superposition'' / Mixed-member majoritarian (MMM) using a single vote
] + ] (FPTP/SMP)
|315
|]
|
|-
|] (South Korea)
|]
|]
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|1 (local districts), 17 supplementary seats (parallel voting), 30 additional seats (AMS),
|''Supermixed'' / Mixed-member majoritarian (MMM):
] (FPTP/SMP) and ] (hybrid of ] and ])
|300
|]
|
|-
|Kuwait
|
|
|
|
|] (SNTV)
|
|
|
|-
|]
|]
|]
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|1 (local districts), 54 (nationwide constituency)
|Parallel voting / ''superposition'' (MMM):
] (open list) + ] (FPTP/SMP)
|90
|]
|
|-
|]
|]
|]
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|1 (local districts), 70 (nationwide constituency)
|Parallel voting / ''superposition'' (MMM):
] (TRS) for 71 seats + ] (]) for 70 seats
|141
|]
|
|-
|]
|]
|]
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|1–2
|] ] (FPTP/SMP) in 87 single-member districts, ] (], ]) in 32 two-member districts (64 seats in ])
|151
|]
|
|-
|]
|]
|]
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|1–3 (local districts), 40 (nationwide constituency)
|''Coexistence+superposition'' (parallel) ''supermixed''/hybrid:
] (TRS) in single-member districts, ] (BV) in dual-member districts, and ] (simple quota largest remainder; closed-list) in larger districts + twice 20 nationally ] (one set of 20 reserved for women)
|157
|]
|
|-
|]
|]
|]
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|24 (nationwide constituency)
|''Superposition'' / Mixed-member majoritarian (MMM) using a single (]) ballot:
] (BV) in single nationwide constituency for 16 seats; ] (8 seats)
|24
|] {{Citation needed|date=January 2022}}
|
|-
|]
|]
|]
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|1–9 (local districts), 66 (nationwide constituency)
|Parallel voting / ''superposition'' (MMM):
] (FPTP/SMP) in single-member districts and ] (BV) in two-seat districts for 66 seats in total (some reserved for Christians) + ] for 66 seats
|132
|]
|In the 1996 elections, 88 PLC members were chosen from several multi-member constituencies via ]
|-
|]
|]
|]
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|
|'']'' mixed majoritarian (MMM):
] (FPTP/SMP) in single-member districts, Saripolo or Sartori method (], but remainders only for those with no seats) in multi-member districts
|71
|]
|
|-
|]
|]
|]
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|1 (local districts), 61 (nationwide constituency)
|Parallel voting / ''superposition'' (MMM):
] (FPTP/SMP) in single-member districts (243 in 2019) + ] (]; modified ] with 3-seat cap and no remainders) (61 in 2019)
|304
|]
|
|-
|]
|]
|]
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|{{Citation needed|date=January 2022}}
|Parallel voting / ''superposition'' (MMM):
] (FPTP/SMP) and ]
|450
|]
|
|-
|]
|
|
|
|
|Majority bonus system (MBS)
|
|]
|
|-
|]
|]
|]
|Mixed-member majoritarian
|73 (constituency), 56 (7 list MSPs elected in each of the 8 regions)
|] (AMS)
|129
|]
|
|-
|]
|
|2017
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|
|Parallel
|165
|]
|
|-
|]
|
|2020
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|
|Parallel
|35
|]
|
|-
|]
|
|2020
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|
|] (FPTP/SMP) and ] (PBV)
|104 (93 directly elected)
|
|
|-
|]
|
|2015
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|
|Parallel
|450
|
|
|-
|]
|Council of States
Only in:

* ''names of cantons''
|
|
|2
|] (SNTV)
|46
|
|
|-
|]
|
|2020
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|
|Parallel
|113
|
|
|-
|]
|
|2020
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|
|Parallel
|63
|
|
|-
|]
|
|2019 (using ])
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|
|Parallel
|500
|
|The next election is scheduled to be held under parallel voting again, after one election (2019) held using a single vote MMP system
|-
| rowspan="2" |] (United Kingdom)
|]
|
|
|
|] (LV)
|
|
|
|-
|]
|
|
|
|] (SNTV)
|
|
|
|-
|]
|
|
|
|
|] (SNTV)
|
|
|
|-
|]
|]
|2020
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|
|Parallel voting (MMM):
] (FPTP/SMP) and ]
|280 (277 directly elected)
|]
|
|-
|]
|]
|]
| Mixed-member majoritarian
|1 (local districts),
10 (proportional constituencies)
| Mixed-member majoritarian (MMM):
210 seats by ] (FPTP/SMP) in local districts

60 seats reserved for women by ]
|270
|]
|Voters cast a single vote
|}


== References == == References ==
{{Reflist|30em}}
<references/>


] ]
] ]

Latest revision as of 18:39, 11 September 2024

Family of electoral systems
It has been suggested that this article be split into a new article titled Winner-take-most representation. (discuss) (August 2024)
A joint Politics and Economics series
Social choice and electoral systems
Single-winner methodsSingle vote - plurality methods

Condorcet methods


Positional voting


Cardinal voting

Proportional representationParty-list

Quota-remainder methods


Approval-based committees


Fractional social choice


Semi-proportional representation

Mixed systemsBy results of combination
By mechanism of combination

By ballot type

Paradoxes and pathologiesSpoiler effects

Pathological response


Strategic voting


Paradoxes of majority rule

Social and collective choiceImpossibility theorems

Positive results

icon Mathematics portal

Semi-proportional representation characterizes multi-winner electoral systems which allow representation of minorities, but are not intended to reflect the strength of the competing political forces in close proportion to the votes they receive. Semi-proportional voting systems are generally used as a compromise between complex and expensive but more-proportional systems (like the single transferable vote) and simple winner-take-all systems. Examples of semi-proportional systems include the single non-transferable vote, limited voting, and parallel voting.

Semi-proportional systems

Most proportional representation systems will not yield precisely proportional outcomes due to the use of election thresholds, small electoral regions, or other implementation details that vary from one elected body to another. However, systems that yield results close to the ideal are generally considered fully-proportional.

The choice to use a semi-proportional electoral system may be a deliberate attempt to find a balance between single-party rule and proportional representation. Semi-proportional systems can allow for fairer representation of those parties that have difficulty gaining even a single seat while retaining the possibility of one party gaining an overall majority of seats even if it receives less than a majority of the votes; they can ensure that the two or three largest parties all have their due share of seats or more while not producing representation for the smallest parties.

Because there are many measures of proportionality, and because there is no objective threshold, opinions may differ on what constitutes a semi-proportional system as opposed to a non-proportional one or a fully proportional system.

Single-vote systems

Election systems in which a party can achieve its due share of seats (proportionality) only by coordinating its voters are usually considered to be semi-proportional. They are not non-proportional or majoritarian, since in the perfect case the outcome will be proportional, but they are not proportional either, since the perfect case is not guaranteed without coordination. Such systems include the single non-transferable vote and cumulative voting, both of which are commonly used to achieve approximately-proportional outcomes while maintaining simplicity and reducing the cost of election administration. Under these systems, parties often coordinate voters by limiting the size of the party slate, or by using complex vote management schemes where voters are asked to randomize which candidate(s) they support.

These systems are notable for the absence of an ordered electoral list. Candidates may coordinate their campaigns, and present or be presented as agents of a party, but voters may choose to support one candidate among the said group but not the others (that is, panachage is permitted).

Single transferable vote

Many writers consider the single transferable vote to be a semi-proportional system because of its substantial favoritism towards major parties, generally caused by a combination of the Droop quota in small districts, as well as the substantial degree of vote management involved when there are exhausted ballots. On the other hand, some authors describe it as a proportional system, on the grounds that it is theoretically weakly proportional in the limit of infinitely-large constituencies. However, it is worth noting that STV is only proportional for solid coalitions, i.e. if voters rank candidates first by party and only then by candidate. As such, the proportionality of STV breaks down if voters are split across party lines or choose to support candidates of different parties.

A major complication with proportionality under STV is the need for constituencies; small constituencies are strongly disproportional, but large constituencies make it difficult or impossible for voters to rank large numbers of candidates, turning the election into a de facto open list PR system, particularly where voters lack any meaningful information about the candidates on their ballot.

The degree of proportionality of the results in a district (and when combined with other district results, the proportionality of results across a country) depends on the number of seats elected in the district. In the 2011 Irish general election, Fine Gael received 45.2% of the seats with just 36.1% of the first preference votes. In the 2020 Irish general election, the Labour Party received 50% more votes than the Social Democrats, but both parties won the same number of seats. Ireland uses districts of 3-7 members.

Similarly, the 1998 Northern Ireland elections resulted in the Ulster Unionists winning more seats than the Social Democratic and Labour Party with a smaller share of the vote.

The proportionality of STV can be controversial, especially in close elections like the 1981 election in Malta. In this election, the Maltese Labour party won a majority of seats despite the Nationalist Party winning a majority of first preference votes. This caused a constitutional crisis, leading to a provision to provide bonus seats in case of disproportional results. These bonus seats were needed in 1987, 1996, and 2008 to prevent further electoral inversions.

The degree of proportionality nationwide is strongly related to the number of seats to be filled in each constituency. In a three-seat constituency using the Droop quota, a full quarter of the vote is wasted. In a nine-seat constituency, only a tenth of the vote is wasted, and a party needs only 10% of the vote to win a seat. Consequently, the best proportionality is achieved when there are a large number of representatives per constituency. The Hare quota is theoretically unbiased, allowing some of the errors in apportionment to cancel out if voters across the whole country. However, it also increases the vulnerability of STV to vote management by large parties, allowing them to win the same number of seats they would have won under Droop.

Partisan systems

Other forms of semi-proportional representation are based on, or at least use, party lists to work. Looking to the electoral systems effectively in use around the world, there are three general methods to reinforce the majoritarian principle of representation (but not necessarily majoritarianism or majority rule, see electoral inversion and plurality) starting from basic PR mechanisms: parallel voting, the majority bonus system (MBS), and extremely reduced constituency magnitude.

In additional member systems (AMS), the number of additional members may not be sufficient to balance the disproportionality of the original system, thereby producing less than proportional results. When this imbalance is created intentionally, the result could be described as a semi-proportional system — for example, in the National Assembly for Wales, where only 33.3% of members are compensatory. The electoral system commonly referred to in Britain as the "additional member system" is also used for the Scottish Parliament and the London Assembly, with generally proportional results. Similarly, in vote transfer based mixed single vote systems, the number of compensatory seats may be too low (or too high) to achieve proportionality. Such a system is used in Hungary in local elections. The "scorporo" system used for the Parliament of Italy from 1993 to 2005 and the electoral system for the National Assembly of Hungary since 1990 are also special cases, based on parallel voting, but also including compensatory mechanisms – which however are insufficient for providing proportional results.

A majority bonus system takes an otherwise proportional system based on multi-member constituencies, and introduces disproportionality by granting additional seats to the first party or alliance. Majority bonuses help produce landslide victories similar to those which occur in elections under plurality systems. The majority bonus system was first introduced by Benito Mussolini to win the election of 1924. It has remained in use in Italy, as well as seeing some use in San Marino, Greece, and France.

The simplest mechanism to reinforce major parties in PR system is to severely restrict the number of seats per electoral district, which increases the Droop quota (the number of votes needed to be guaranteed a seat).

The last main group usually considered semi-proportional consists of parallel voting models. The system used for the Chamber of Deputies of Mexico since 1996 is considered a parallel voting system, modified by a list-seat ceiling (8%) for over-representation of parties.

Usage

This table is incomplete; you can help by expanding it.
This section does not cite any sources. Please help improve this section by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed.
Find sources: "Semi-proportional representation" – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (June 2024) (Learn how and when to remove this message)
Country Legislative body Latest election (year) Type of majoritarian system (Seats per

constituency)

Electoral system Total seats Governmental system Notes
Andorra General Council 2018 Mixed-member majoritarian 2 (local districts) / 14 (nationwide constituency) Parallel voting / superposition (MMM):

Party block voting (PBV) locally + list PR nationwide

28 Parliamentary system
Democratic Republic of the Congo National Assembly 2018 Mixed-member majoritarian 1–17 Coexistence mixed majoritarian (MMM):

First-past-the-post (FPTP/SMP) in single-member districts and List PR in multi-member districts (Largest remainder)

500
Djibouti National Assembly 2018 Mixed-member majoritarian 3–28 Fusion / majority jackpot (MBS):

80% of seats (rounded to the nearest integer) in each constituency are awarded to the party receiving the most votes (party block voting), remaining seats are allocated proportionally to other parties receiving over 10% (closed list, D'Hondt method)

65 Presidential system
France French Polynesia Assembly 2018 Mixed-member majoritarian 4–17 Two-round majority bonus system (MBS) in multi-member constituencies 57
Georgia Parliament 2020 Mixed-member majoritarian 1 (local districts),

120 (national constituency)

Parallel voting / superposition (MMM):

Party-list PR (closed list) + First-past-the-post (FPTP/SMP)

150 Parliamentary system
Greece Mixed-member majoritarian Majority bonus system (MBS)
Guinea National Assembly 2020 Mixed-member majoritarian 1 (local districts),

76 (national constituency)

Parallel voting / superposition (MMM):

Party-list PR (Hare quota) + First-past-the-post (FPTP/SMP)

114
Hungary National Assembly (Országgyűlés) 2018 Mixed-member majoritarian 1 (local districts), 93 (national constituency) Supermixed / Mixed-member majoritarian (MMM):

First-past-the-post (FPTP/SMP) + national list-PR for 93 seats (combination of parallel voting and positive vote transfer)

199 Parliamentary system Before the 2014, a different mixed system was used with a two-round system in single-member districts
Iraq Single non-transferable vote (SNTV)
Italy Chamber of Deputies 2018 Mixed-member majoritarian 1 (local districts), 12 (Italians abroad constituency), ?-? (multi-member districts) Superposition / Mixed-member majoritarian (MMM) using a single vote

List PR + First-past-the-post (FPTP/SMP)

630 Parliamentary system
Senate 2018 Mixed-member majoritarian 1 (local districts), 6 (Italians abroad constituency), ?-? (multi-member districts) Superposition / Mixed-member majoritarian (MMM) using a single vote

List PR + First-past-the-post (FPTP/SMP)

315 Parliamentary system
Republic of Korea (South Korea) National Assembly 2020 Mixed-member majoritarian 1 (local districts), 17 supplementary seats (parallel voting), 30 additional seats (AMS), Supermixed / Mixed-member majoritarian (MMM):

First-past-the-post (FPTP/SMP) and List PR (hybrid of parallel voting and AMS)

300 Presidential system
Kuwait Single non-transferable vote (SNTV)
Kyrgyzstan Supreme Council 2021 Mixed-member majoritarian 1 (local districts), 54 (nationwide constituency) Parallel voting / superposition (MMM):

Party-list PR (open list) + First-past-the-post (FPTP/SMP)

90 Presidential system
Lithuania Seimas 2020 Mixed-member majoritarian 1 (local districts), 70 (nationwide constituency) Parallel voting / superposition (MMM):

Two-round system (TRS) for 71 seats + List PR (Largest remainder) for 70 seats

141 Semi-presidential system
Madagascar National Assembly 2019 Mixed-member majoritarian 1–2 Coexistence: First-past-the-post (FPTP/SMP) in 87 single-member districts, party-list PR (Closed list, highest averages method) in 32 two-member districts (64 seats in binomial system) 151 Semi-presidential system
Mauritania National Assembly 2018 Mixed-member majoritarian 1–3 (local districts), 40 (nationwide constituency) Coexistence+superposition (parallel) supermixed/hybrid:

Two-round system (TRS) in single-member districts, two-round block voting (BV) in dual-member districts, and List PR (simple quota largest remainder; closed-list) in larger districts + twice 20 nationally List PR (one set of 20 reserved for women)

157 Semi-presidential system
Monaco National Council 2018 Mixed-member majoritarian 24 (nationwide constituency) Superposition / Mixed-member majoritarian (MMM) using a single (panachage) ballot:

Plurality block voting (BV) in single nationwide constituency for 16 seats; D'Hondt method (8 seats)

24 Parliamentary system
Palestine Legislative Council 2006 Mixed-member majoritarian 1–9 (local districts), 66 (nationwide constituency) Parallel voting / superposition (MMM):

First-past-the-post (FPTP/SMP) in single-member districts and Plurality block voting (BV) in two-seat districts for 66 seats in total (some reserved for Christians) + List PR for 66 seats

132 Semi-presidential system In the 1996 elections, 88 PLC members were chosen from several multi-member constituencies via block voting
Panama National Assembly 2019 Mixed-member majoritarian Coexistence mixed majoritarian (MMM):

First-past-the-post (FPTP/SMP) in single-member districts, Saripolo or Sartori method (Largest remainder, but remainders only for those with no seats) in multi-member districts

71 Presidential system
Philippines House of Representatives 2019 Mixed-member majoritarian 1 (local districts), 61 (nationwide constituency) Parallel voting / superposition (MMM):

First-past-the-post (FPTP/SMP) in single-member districts (243 in 2019) + List PR (closed lists; modified Hare quota with 3-seat cap and no remainders) (61 in 2019)

304 Presidential system
Russian Federation State Duma 2021 Mixed-member majoritarian Parallel voting / superposition (MMM):

First-past-the-post (FPTP/SMP) and List PR

450 Semi-presidential system
San Marino Majority bonus system (MBS) Parliamentary system
Scotland Parliament 2021 Mixed-member majoritarian 73 (constituency), 56 (7 list MSPs elected in each of the 8 regions) Additional Member System (AMS) 129 Parliamentary system
Senegal 2017 Mixed-member majoritarian Parallel 165 Presidential system
Seychelles 2020 Mixed-member majoritarian Parallel 35 Presidential system
Singapore 2020 Mixed-member majoritarian First-past-the-post (FPTP/SMP) and party block voting (PBV) 104 (93 directly elected)
Sudan 2015 Mixed-member majoritarian Parallel 450
Switzerland Council of States

Only in:

  • names of cantons
2 Single non-transferable vote (SNTV) 46
Taiwan 2020 Mixed-member majoritarian Parallel 113
Tajikistan 2020 Mixed-member majoritarian Parallel 63
Thailand 2019 (using MMP) Mixed-member majoritarian Parallel 500 The next election is scheduled to be held under parallel voting again, after one election (2019) held using a single vote MMP system
British Overseas Territories (United Kingdom) Gibraltar Limited voting (LV)
Pitcairn Islands Single non-transferable vote (SNTV)
Vanuatu Single non-transferable vote (SNTV)
Venezuela National Assembly 2020 Mixed-member majoritarian Parallel voting (MMM):

First-past-the-post (FPTP/SMP) and list PR

280 (277 directly elected) Presidential system
Zimbabwe National Assembly 2018 Mixed-member majoritarian 1 (local districts),

10 (proportional constituencies)

Mixed-member majoritarian (MMM):

210 seats by first-past-the-post (FPTP/SMP) in local districts

60 seats reserved for women by list PR

270 Presidential system Voters cast a single vote

References

  1. Douglas J. Amy. "Semiproportional voting systems". Retrieved 19 June 2011.
  2. Giovanni Sartori (2005). Parties and Party Systems. A framework for analysis. European Consortium for Political Research. ISBN 9780954796617.
  3. Douglas J. Amy (2000). Behind the Ballot Box: A Citizen's Guide to Voting Systems. Greenwood Publishing Group. ISBN 9780275965860.
  4. P. Kestelman (June 2005). "Apportionment and Proportionality: A Measured View" (PDF). Retrieved 19 June 2011.
  5. Barry R. Weingast; Donald A. Wittman (19 October 2006). The Oxford handbook of political economy. Oxford University Press. pp. 105–. ISBN 978-0-19-927222-8. Retrieved 19 June 2011.
  6. "Semi-Proportional Electoral Methods". Retrieved 19 June 2011.
  7. Norris, Pippa (1997). "Choosing Electoral Systems: Proportional, Majoritarian and Mixed Systems" (PDF). Harvard University.
  8. David M. Farrell Electoral Systems (2011)
  9. Golosov, G. V. (2013). "The Case for Mixed Single Vote Electoral Systems". The Journal of Social, Political, and Economic Studies.
  10. "2010. évi L. törvény a helyi önkormányzati képviselők és polgármesterek választásáról" [Act L. of 2010. on the election of local government representatives and mayors] (in Hungarian).
Categories:
Semi-proportional representation: Difference between revisions Add topic